Open Access Open Access  Restricted Access Subscription Access
Open Access Open Access Open Access  Restricted Access Restricted Access Subscription Access

Strategy, Execution and Idle Rationality


Affiliations
1 Australian Graduate School of Management Gate 11 Botany Street Sydney New South Wales 2052, Australia
     

   Subscribe/Renew Journal


Despite having the capability to act, firms sometimes lapse, blunder, or squander opportunities. Modern theories of the firm acknowledge the effects of uncertainty, transaction costs and agency problems on firm conduct, but they do not recognize the consequences of "execution holes" - the primitive failure to act. If execution holes exist, rationality is not bounded but "idle," and strategic heterogeneity emerges even in the absence of market imperfections such as mobility or resource imitation barriers. This paper contrasts the "barrier logic" of conventional strategy theory with an "execution logic" derived from the existence of execution holes. In a simulation model, the paper compares efficiency losses produced by market imperfections with those produced by execution holes. By analogy to x-inefficiency, the paper discusses "x-factors" - solvable unsolved problems - and identifies the opportunity costs of pursuing barrier-driven, market-sheltering strategies when fundamental strategic problems remain unsolved.

Keywords

Idle Rationality, Bounded Rationality, Perfect Rationality, Strategic Capital Share, Strategic Heterogeneity
User
Notifications

  • Amit, R. and Schoemaker, P.J. (1993), Strategic assets and organizational rent, Strategic Management Journal 14: 33-46.
  • Arend, R. J. (2003), Revisiting the Logical and Research Considerations of Competitive Advantage, Strategic Management Journal 24: 279-284.
  • Argenti, J. (1976), Corporate Collapse: The causes and symptoms, McGraw-Hill, New York.
  • Arthur, W.B. (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.
  • Barnett, W.P and Hansen, M.T. (1996), The red queen in organizational evolution, Strategic Management Journal 17: 139-157.
  • Barney J. (1986), Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck and business strategy, Management Science 32: 1231-1241.
  • Barney, J. (1991), Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage, Journal of Management 17: 99-120.
  • Barney, J. (2001), Is the resource-based “view” a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes, Academy of Management Review 26: 41-56.
  • Bergsman, J. (1974), Commercial policy, allocative efficiency, and x-efficiency, Quarterly Journal of Economics 88: 409-433.
  • Bettman, J. and Weitz, B. (1983), Attributions in the board room: Causal reasoning in corporate annual reports, Administrative Science Quarterly 28: 165-183.
  • Braybrooke, D. and Lindblom, C.E. (1963), A Strategy of Decision, Free Press, New York.
  • Bromiley, P. and L. Fleming (2002), The resource-based view of strategy: an evolutionist’s critique, in M. Augier and J. March (eds.), The Economics of Choice, Change and Organizations: Essays in Memory of Richard Cyert, pp. 319-336, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Brunsson, N. (1982), The irrationality of action and action rationality: Decisions, ideologies and organizational actions, Journal of Management Studies 19: 29-44.
  • Button, K.J. (1985), Potential differences in x-inefficiency between industrial sectors in the United Kingdom, Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 25: 85-95.
  • Button, K.J. and Weyman-Jones, T.G. (1992), Ownership structure, institutional organization, and measured x-efficiency, American Economic Review 82: 439-445.
  • Camerer, C. and Lovallo, D. (1999), Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. American Economic Review 89(1): 306-318.
  • Caves, R.E. and Porter, M.E. (1977), From entry barriers to mobility barriers, Quarterly Journal of Economics 91: 241-261.
  • Christensen, C.M. (2000), The Innovator’s Dilemma, Harper, New York.
  • Coff, R.W. (1999), When competitive advantage doesn’t lead to performance: The resource-based view and stakeholder bargaining power, Organization Science 10: 119-133.
  • Cohen, M.D. and March, J.G. (1974), Leadership and Ambiguity (2 ed), Harvard Press, Boston.
  • Cohen, M.D., March, J.G., and Olsen, J.P. (1972), A garbage can model of organizational choice, Administrative Science Quarterly 17: 1-25.
  • Cubbin, J. and Geroski, P. (1987), The convergence of profits in the long run: Inter-firm and inter-industry comparisons, Journal of Industrial Economics 35: 427-442.
  • Cyert, R.M. and March, J.G. (1963), A Behavioral Theory of the Firm, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
  • Darnell, C. and Rumpf, J. (1996), Harley-Davidson, Inc, in M.A. Hitt, R.D. Ireland, and R.E. Hoskisson, Strategic Management: Competitiveness and Globalization, West, Minneapolis-St. Paul, c371-c384.
  • De Alessi, L. (1983), Property rights, transaction costs, and x-efficiency: An essay in economic theory, American Economic Review 73(1): 64-81.
  • Fichman, M. and Levinthal, D. (1991), Honeymoons and the liability of adolescence: A new perspective on duration dependence in social and organizational relationships, Academy of Management Review 16: 442-460.
  • Finkelstein, S. (2003), Why Smart Executives Fail, Penguin Books, New York.
  • Frantz, R. (1988), X-efficiency: Theory, Evidence and Applications, Kluwer, Boston.
  • Frantz, R. (1992), X-efficiency and allocative efficiency: What have we learned? American Economic Review 82: 434-438.
  • Gerstner, L.V. (2002), Who Says Elephants Can’t Dance? Inside IBM’s Historic Turnaround, Harper Business, New York.
  • Godfrey, P. and Hill, C.W.L. (1995), The problem of unobservables in strategic management research, Strategic Management Journal 16: 519-533.
  • Hayes, R.H. and Upton, D.M. (1998), Operations-based strategy, California Management Review 40(4): 8-25.
  • Henderson, J.M. and Quandt, R.E. (1980), Microeconomic Theory (3 ed), McGraw-Hill, New York.
  • Hofer, C. and Schendel, D. (1978), Strategy Formulation: Analytical Concepts, West, St. Paul.
  • Holmstrom, B. and Milgrom, P. (1994), The firm as an incentive system, American Economic Review 84: 972-991.
  • Jacobsen, R. (1988), The persistence of abnormal returns, Strategic Management Journal 9: 415-430.
  • Jameson, K. (1972), Comment of the theory and measurement of dynamic x-efficiency, Quarterly Journal of Economics 86: 313-326.
  • Jensen, M. and Murphy, K.J. (1990), Performance pay and top management incentives, Journal of Political Economy 98: 225-264.
  • Johnston, J. (1963). The productivity of management consultants, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A: 237-249.
  • Kahneman, D. and Lovallo, D. (1993), Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk-taking, Management Science 39: 17-31.
  • Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1973), On the psychology of prediction, Psychological Review 80: 237-251.
  • Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1982), The simulation heuristic. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, and A. Tversky (eds.), Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, pp. 201-208, Cambridge University Press, New York.
  • Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (2000), Choices, Values and Frames. Cambridge Press, New York.
  • Knott, A.M. (2003), Persistent heterogeneity and sustainable innovation, Strategic Management Journal 24: 687-705.
  • Laffont, J. and Tirole, J. (1986), Using cost observations to regulate firms, Journal of Political Economy 94: 614-641.
  • Leibenstein, H. (1966), Allocative efficiency vs. x-efficiency, American Economic Review 56: 392-415.
  • Leibenstein, H. (1976), Beyond Economic Man, Harvard Press, Cambridge, MA.
  • Leibenstein, H. (1978), X-efficiency Xists: Reply to an Xorcist, American Economic Review 56: 203-211.
  • Leibenstein, H. (1980), Microeconomics and x-efficiency theory: If there is no crisis, there ought to be, The Public Interest: The Crisis in Economic Theory, 1980 special issue: 97-110.
  • Leibenstein, H. and Maital, S. (1992), Empirical estimation and partitioning of x-inefficiency: A data-envelopment approach, American Economic Review 82: 428-433.
  • Levinthal, D.A. (1997), Adaptation on rugged landscapes, Management Science 43: 934-950.
  • Levinthal, D.A. (1991), Random walks and organizational mortality, Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 397-420.
  • Lieberman, M. (1989), The learning curve, technology barriers to entry, and competitive survival in the chemical processing industries, Strategic Management Journal 10: 431-447.
  • Lindblom, C.E. (1968), The Policy-Making Process, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs.
  • Lippman, S.A. and Rumelt, R.P. (1982), Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under competition. Bell Journal of Economics 13: 418-438.
  • Lipsky, M. (1978), Standing the study of public policy implementation on its head, in W.D. Burnham and M.W. Weinberg (eds.), American Politics and Public Policy, pp. 391-402, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
  • Lowenstein, R. (2000), When Genius Failed, Random House, New York.
  • March, J.G. and Simon, H.A. (1958), Organizations, Wiley & Sons, New York.
  • March, J.G. (1988), Decisions and Organizations, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.
  • Majone, G. and Wildavsky, A. (1978), Implementation as evolution, Policy Studies Review Annual 2: 103-117.
  • McEvily, S., Das, S., and McCabe, K. (2000), Avoiding competence substitution through knowledge sharing, Academy of Management Review 25: 294-311.
  • Mezias, J.M. and Starbuck, W.M. (2003), Studying the accuracy of managers’ perceptions: The odyssey continues, British Journal of Management 14: 3-17.
  • Miles, G., Snow, C.C., and Sharfman, M.P. (1993), Industry variety and performance, Strategic Management Journal 14: 163-177.
  • Miller, D. (1990), The Icarus Paradox, Harper Business, New York.
  • Miller, D. T. & Ross, M. (1975), Self-serving biases in the attribution of causality. Fact or fiction? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 82: 213-225.
  • Mintzberg, H. (1994), The Rise and Fall of Strategic Planning, Free Press, New York.
  • Mintzberg, H., Raisinghani, D. and Theoret, A. (1976), The structure of “unstructured” decision processes, Adminstrative Science Quarterly 21: 246-275.
  • Mintzberg, H. and McHugh, A. (1985), Strategy formation in an adhocracy, Administrative Science Quarterly 30: 160-197.
  • Mintzberg,H. and Waters, J.S. (1982), Tracking strategy in an entrepreneurial firm, Academy of Management Journal 25: 465-499.
  • Nelson, R.R. (1991), Why do firms differ, and how does it matter?, Strategic Management Journal 12: 61-74.
  • Nelson, R.R. and Winter, S.G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Belknap Press, Cambridge, MA.
  • Newell, A. and Simon, H.A. (1972), Human Problem Solving, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs.
  • Peristiani, S. (1997), Do mergers improve the x-efficiency and scale efficiency of U.S. banks? Evidence from the 1980s, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29: 326-337.
  • Peteraf, M. (1993), The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal 14: 179-191.
  • Porter, M.E. (1980), Competitive Strategy, Free Press, New York.
  • Powell, T.C. (2001), Competitive advantage: Logical and philosophical considerations, Strategic Management Journal 22: 875-888.
  • Powell, T.C. (2002), The philosophy of strategy, Strategic Management Journal 23: 873-880.
  • Powell, T.C. (2003a), Varieties of competitive parity, Strategic Management Journal 24: 61-86.
  • Powell, T.C. (2003b), Strategy without ontology, Strategic Management Journal 24: 285-291.
  • Priem, R.L. and Butler, J.E. (2001), Is the resource-based “view” a useful perspective for strategic management research?, Academy of Management Review 28: 22-40.
  • Primeaux, W.J. (1977), An assessment of x-efficiency gained through competition, Review of Economics and Statistics 59: 105-108.
  • Reufli, T.W. and Wiggins, R.R. (2003), Industry and corporate effects on business performance: A non-parametric approach, Strategic Management Journal 24: 861-879.
  • Rivkin, J.W. (2000), Imitation of complex strategies, Management Science 46: 824-844.
  • Roberts, P.W. (1999), Product innovation, product-market competition and persistent profitability in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry, Strategic Management Journal 20: 655-670.
  • Ross, S. (1973), The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem, American Economic Review 63: 134-139.
  • Rumelt, R.P. (1984), Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In R. Lamb (ed.), Competitive Strategic Management, pp. 556-570, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
  • Rumelt, R.P. (1987), Theory, strategy and entrepreneurship, in D.J. Teece (ed.), The Competitive Challenge, pp. 137-158, Harper and Row, New York.
  • Salancik, G.A. & Meindl, J.R (1984), Corporate attributions as strategic illusions of management control, Administrative Science Quarterly 29(2): 238-254.
  • Salter, W.E. (1960), Productivity and Technical Change, Cambridge Press: Cambridge, UK
  • Scherer, F.M. and Ross, D. (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Houghton-Mifflin, Boston.
  • Shelton, J.P. (1967), Allocative efficiency vs. x-efficiency – comment, American Economic Review 57: 1252-1258.
  • Shen, T.Y. (1973), Technology diffusion, substitution and x-efficiency, Econometrica 41: 263-284.
  • Simon, H.A. (1955), A behavioral model of rational choice, Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99-118.
  • Simon H.A. (1956), Rational choice and the structure of the environment, Psychological Review 63: 129-138.
  • Simon, H.A. (1972), Theories of bounded rationality, in C.B. Radner and R. Radner (eds.), Decision and Organization, pp. 161-176, North-Holland Publishing, Amsterdam.
  • Spence, A.M. (1981), The learning curve and competition, Bell Journal of Economics 12: 49-70.
  • Starbuck, W.H. (1983), Organizations as action generators, American Sociological Review 48: 91-102.
  • Staw, B. M. (1976), Knee-deep in the big muddy: A study of escalating commitment to a failing course of action, Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 16: 27-44.
  • Stigler, G. (1976), The Xistence of X-efficiency, American Economic Review 66: 213-216.
  • Stinchcombe, A. (1965), Organizations and social structure, in J.G. March (ed.), Handbook of Organizations, pp. 142-193, Rand-McNally, Chicago.
  • Teece, D., Pisano, G. and Schuen, A. (1997), Dynamic capabilities and strategic management, Strategic Management Journal 18: 509-533.
  • Teece, D. J. (1998), Capturing value from knowledge assets, California Management Review 40(3): 55-79.
  • Vasconcellos, J.A.S. and Hambrick, D.C. (1989), Key success factors: Test of a general theory in the mature industrial-product sector, Strategic Management Journal 10: 367-382.
  • Waring, G. (1996), Industry differences in the persistence of firm-specific returns, American Economic Review 86: 1253-1264.
  • Weick, K.E. (1987), Substitutes for strategy, in D.J. Teece (ed.), The Competitive Challenge, pp. 221-233, Harper and Row, New York.
  • Wernerfelt, B. (1984), A resource-based view of the firm, Strategic Management Journal 5: 171-180.
  • Wildavsky, A. (1971), Does planning work?, The Public Interest, Summer: 95-104.
  • Wildavsky, A. (1979), Speaking Truth to Power: The Art and Craft of Policy Analysis, Little, Brown & Co., Toronto.
  • Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press, New York.
  • Winter, S. (2000), The satisficing principle in capability learning, Strategic Management Journal 21: 981-996.
  • Zajac, E. and Bazerman, M. (1991), Blind spots in industry and competitor analysis: Implications of interfirm (mis)perceptions for strategic decisions, Academy of Management Review 16: 37-56.

Abstract Views: 283

PDF Views: 1




  • Strategy, Execution and Idle Rationality

Abstract Views: 283  |  PDF Views: 1

Authors

Thomas C Powell
Australian Graduate School of Management Gate 11 Botany Street Sydney New South Wales 2052, Australia

Abstract


Despite having the capability to act, firms sometimes lapse, blunder, or squander opportunities. Modern theories of the firm acknowledge the effects of uncertainty, transaction costs and agency problems on firm conduct, but they do not recognize the consequences of "execution holes" - the primitive failure to act. If execution holes exist, rationality is not bounded but "idle," and strategic heterogeneity emerges even in the absence of market imperfections such as mobility or resource imitation barriers. This paper contrasts the "barrier logic" of conventional strategy theory with an "execution logic" derived from the existence of execution holes. In a simulation model, the paper compares efficiency losses produced by market imperfections with those produced by execution holes. By analogy to x-inefficiency, the paper discusses "x-factors" - solvable unsolved problems - and identifies the opportunity costs of pursuing barrier-driven, market-sheltering strategies when fundamental strategic problems remain unsolved.

Keywords


Idle Rationality, Bounded Rationality, Perfect Rationality, Strategic Capital Share, Strategic Heterogeneity

References